권호기사보기
기사명 | 저자명 | 페이지 | 원문 | 기사목차 |
---|
대표형(전거형, Authority) | 생물정보 | 이형(異形, Variant) | 소속 | 직위 | 직업 | 활동분야 | 주기 | 서지 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
연구/단체명을 입력해주세요. |
|
|
|
|
|
* 주제를 선택하시면 검색 상세로 이동합니다.
본 논문은 전통적 관료제를 자유주의적으로 재해석하고, 공감(共感)의 강박(强迫)이지배적인 한국적 상황에서 여전히 효율적인 경영제도임을 논증한다. 기업 혹은 관료제에대한 일상적 이해는 근대적 관료제 그 자체에 대한 오독(誤讀)의 결과이고, 근대적관료제는 Weber(1968)와 Taylor(1911)에서 설파된 대로 여전히 효율적인 경영제도라고주장한다. 특히, 관료제의 본질은 (1) 리바이어던(Leviathan)과 같은 의사결정권의 집중화와 무관하며, (2) 직무의 완벽한 사전 설계와도 무관하며, (3) 이방인에 대한 불확실성을낮추기 위해 행위의 표준화를 꾀하는 즉 일하는 방식을 설계하는 데 있음을 보여주었다.
특히, (1) 도덕률에 근거한 행위의 규율을 합리적 계산의 자유주의적 전통으로 대체하려고 하는 한, (2) 잉여 소비를 가능케 하는 대량생산 기술을 포기하지 않는 한, 그리고(3) 이방인과의 대규모 협업이 경제적 생산과 교환을 지탱하는 한, 근대적 관료제는지속 가능한 생산의 형식임을 규명한다. 마지막으로 관료제는 시장과 구별되는 근대적제도이며 서로 다른 경제의 문제를 풀어내기 때문에, 양자간의 공진화에 의해 근대성이유지될 것임을 밝힌다.
continues to work in an efficient manner in a contemporary market. In particular, this study begins with the observation that the mis-understanding of modern bureaucracy underlies new management techniques aimed at renovating obsolete managerial practices and sheds a new light onto the essence of modern bureaucracy by opting for perspectives from Max Weber and Fredrick Taylor. Moreover,it suggests that bureaucracy is a modern production mode distinct from the market and that for the very reason, the modernity of a contemporary society will be sustainable to the extent that the two distinct modes of modern production, i.e., the market and the firm, co-exist and thus co-evolve.
The critics of the Weber-Taylorian bureaucracy (WT bureaucracy henceforth) have been proposing so-called new management techniques to the corporate world, which chases constantly after ever-growing profits in the name of competitive advantage and value creation. They do so either by disregarding the bureaucracy as a pre-modern mode of organizing exchange (Jensen & Meckling,1976; Williamson, 1985), by lamenting it as the root of a pathological modernity (Roethlisberger & Dickson, 1939; Schumacher, 1979), or by diagnosing it as the inefficient execution of modern production (Hammer & Champy, 1993; Huselid, 1995). Despite the subtleties of their corrective measures, these new management techniques as presented so far have one thing in common: the enlarged autonomy of the individual as the modern self. Managerial practices that draw on theories such as self-determination theory (Ryan & Deci, 2000) or positive psychology in general demonstrate this tendency clearly.
Of course, communitarian approach, one of the widely accepted new management techniques,objects arguably the concept of independent, self-governed individuals that are detached from their society (Adler & Heckscher, 2006; MacIntyre, 1981). Yet, it is equally true that even the communitarian self, well situated in social and cultural accumulation of past economic practices,is the modern self that seeks to reconcile his or her liberty of choice to the living world of cumulative social practices, namely, the history of a community. Whether new techniques endorse libertarianism or communitarianism, they all invite the concept of the modern self to their solutions and presume that the WT bureaucracy is a place reserved for Leviathan to exercise his power without consent and that it is not sufficiently modernized.
This study however suggests otherwise. The reasons are as follows.
First, as Mintzberg (1983) clearly illustrates, the WT bureaucracy has nothing to do with the centralization of decision rights, as opposed to a mistaken view of a one-man ruling company,which is commonly found in economic writings such as transaction cost economics and organizational economics (Aghion & Tirole, 1997; Alchian & Demsetz, 1972; Hart, 1990) and which Weber (1968) himself characterized as charismatic authority, distinct from rational authority or bureaucratic control. You may have a bureaucracy with a decentralized or centralized decision-making process.
Rather, the essence of the WT bureaucracy is the standardization of behavior through the design of formal documents that codify the best possible working knowledge for a task in question as chosen and evaluated by a specialist, i.e., a manager. This standardization of the process (and in some cases the input as is found in collegial bureaucracy) sets the ground for the division of labor between employees and the management, leaving the room for the gains of specialization,another source of the economic efficiency of the firm over the market contract.
Second, unlike the criticism that the WT bureaucracy is too slow to adapt to contemporary,fast-changing modern economy, the WT bureaucracy remains to be effective and efficient even in the course of new product developments, whose high task and demand uncertainties are thought to favor an organic or self-autonomous work groups, not rigid formal hierarchy. As is already well detected by Schumpeterian scholars (Bae & Koo, 2009; Schumpeter, 1942) and organization theories such as Cyert and March (1963) and Stichcombe (1990), the routinization of such complex and uncertainty ridden tasks is critical to the efficient operation of the firm, without which a stable cooperation as well as the long-term and large-scaled investment of capital to such cooperation is hard to obtain and sustain.
One related issue that remains is the supposedly impossibility of ex ante intervention. As is commonly observed and heard of, the critics of the WT bureaucracy tend to point to the red tapes, i.e., the inflexible application of rules to changing task environments, further suggesting that it is practically impossible to design rules to regulate decisions under all the possible contingencies so that the inefficiency of the bureaucracy is inevitable. However, this claim of the impossible ex ante intervention contributes to unveiling the very advantage of the bureaucracy over the market or market contracts.
The reasons are twofold. First, the impossibility of ex ante intervention is equally applicable to the market, which underlies the presence of transaction costs associated with any economic exchange (e.g., Coase, 1937; Williamson, 1975, 1985). The very reason why some of transactions are completed through the firm or hierarchy, not through the market is that it is difficult, or more precisely, virtually impossible to draft and design a market contract or contingency claims in a way that shields parties to an exchange against actions in future unforeseen conditions that are not specified and not agreeable by either of the parties involved. This suggests that neither the bureaucratic control nor the market contract is free from the impossibility of ex ante intervention.
Transaction cost economists further observe that the bureaucratic control would be more efficient than the market contract or voluntary negotiation when the frequency of the exchange between two parties is high, the uncertain contingencies of the exchange is high, and two parties make asset-specific investments into the exchange (Williamson, 1985).
Second, as is well illustrated by Arrow (1951), the goal or objective of a group cannot be derived rationally from the simple aggregation of individual goals or preferences, which are by nature intransitive and incompatible, i.e., goal incongruence in an Ouchi’s (1980) sense. Naturally,individuals struggle to impose their own interests into the goal of a group that they belong to.
When you have only bilateral interdependence to consider, the resolution of such a struggle requires at best a voluntary negotiation between parties to an exchange, a case that is depicted by Coase (1937). However, the firm consists of multiple contracts among multiple individuals so that not bilateral but multilateral dependence constitutes and complicates the process of negotiation in the firm. When these multiple parties of incompatible preferences are involved in joint production activities, a market-like negotiation may lead to ceaseless rounds of debates and conflicts: when a resolution of bilateral dependence between two parties may pose a problem to dependence between the other parties, whose resolution in turn nullifies a previous resolution of dependence between the focal two parties (e.g., Miller, 1992). The WT bureaucracy could serve as providing an effective resolution to these circular conflicts by letting the choices of the organization members to get bounded by common rules, i.e., bureaucratic rules (e.g., Adler, Goldoftas, & Levine, 1999).
These rules work as insulating the firm and its members from uncontrollable feedbacks that arise internally from political activities at the workplace as well as from external market competition.
That is, everybody faces the same or standardized constraints, with which he or she simplifies possible actions from the other parties and thus develop a better capacity to reconcile their interests with others. Indeed, James March documented the firm as a collection of competing political coalitions, illuminating successfully that the rule-based bargaining process inside the firm help stabilize cooperation among coalition members of apparently conflicting preferences, which is essential for the long-term and large-scaled capital investment, a condition for evolutionary efficiency of any economic institutions (e.g., Cyert & March, 1963).
In short, this study opts for a liberal equalitarianism perspective (e.g., Rawls, 1971) and seeks to re-examine the basis of the WT bureaucracy. In doing so, it shows that the bureaucratic rules are the bearers of long-term cooperation at large scale; that these rules or the design of tasks serves as alleviating unchosen inequality among workers such as the variations in natural talents or innate productivities; and that the competitive advantage of the firm, or organizational efficiency,may increase insofar as the organizing principle of the firm becomes remote from the market contract and remains closer to the original nature of the WT bureaucracy.기사명 | 저자명 | 페이지 | 원문 | 목차 |
---|---|---|---|---|
서론 : 경영 패러다임 변화의 현상과 해석 | 배종석 | pp.1-34 |
|
|
공공-민간 경영 패러다임의 융합적 전환 : 변화의 추세와 조직의 대응 | 장용석, 조희진 | pp.69-104 |
|
|
경제윤리의 관점에서 바라본 자본주의의 미래와 기업의 사회적 책임 | 정재호, 장하성 | pp.35-67 |
|
|
경영 패러다임의 사회적 기원과 그 진화 : 새로운 경영담론에 대한 해석을 중심으로 | 정동일 | pp.105-151 |
|
|
기업과 시장의 구별짓기 : 기업이론 관점에서의 관료제 | 배종훈 | pp.153-193 |
|
|
위기의 자본주의 : 경영과 조직 이론에 관한 새로운 이해 | 유태영, 권석균 | pp.195-227 |
|
|
상호작용 공정성과 과업성과 : 리더인정 및 심리적 계약의 매개효과 | 손승연, 박희태, 윤석화 | pp.229-260 |
|
|
How Performance Matters : The Impact of Multi-Level Performance Framing on Competitive Behaviors | 정의교 | pp.261-296 |
|
|
A Multidimensional Model of Institutional Embeddedness: The Adoption of Unconventional Therapies by Conventional Hospitals | 이상묵, 박상찬 | pp.297-330 |
|
|
리더의 참여적 의사결정이 조직구성원들의 창의적행동과 성과에 미치는 영향 : 심리적 임파워먼트와직무몰입의 역할을 중심으로 | 김정식, 차동옥 | pp.331-370 |
|
|
일-가정 상호작용과 참살이(well-being)와의 관계 : 긍정의 역할 | 이명신 | pp.371-410 |
|
번호 | 참고문헌 | 국회도서관 소장유무 |
---|---|---|
1 | Organizational learning ![]() |
미소장 |
2 | 인적 '가치창출'과 '인간가치' 창출 : 경영의 철학적 기반 | 소장 |
3 | 경쟁적 패러다임과 인사조직연구 : 자유주의와 공동체주의를 중심으로 | 소장 |
4 | 장용석, 조희진. 2013. 경영 패러다임의 융합적 전환과 조직의 대응: 사회학적 관점에서의 경영.한국인사조직학회 동계 심포지엄. | 미소장 |
5 | 정동일. 2013. 새로운 경영 담론에 대한 해석: 철학적 관점에서의 경영. 한국인사조직학회 동계심포지엄. | 미소장 |
6 | 정재호. 2013. 자본주의의 미래와 기업의 역할: 경제와 윤리 관점에서의 기업. 한국인사조직학회동계 심포지엄. | 미소장 |
7 | 한병철. 2010. 「피로사회」서울: 문학과 지성. | 미소장 |
8 | Organization Science ![]() |
미소장 |
9 | Two Types of Bureaucracy: Enabling and Coercive ![]() |
미소장 |
10 | Adler, P.S., & Heckscher, C. 2006. Towards collaborative community. In C. Heckscher & P. Adler (eds.), The Firm as a Collaborative Community: Reconsidering Trust in the Knowledge Economy. NY: Oxford University Press: 11-105. | 미소장 |
11 | Flexibility versus Efficiency? A Case Study of Model Changeovers in the Toyota Production System ![]() |
미소장 |
12 | Formal and Real Authority in Organizations ![]() |
미소장 |
13 | Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization ![]() |
미소장 |
14 | Arendt, H. 1958. The Human Condition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. | 미소장 |
15 | Arrow, K.J. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Value. New York: Wiley. | 미소장 |
16 | Arrow, K.J. 1974. The Limits of Organization. New York: W. W. Norton and Company. | 미소장 |
17 | Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy ![]() |
미소장 |
18 | Cooperative Exchange with Substitutable Ties and Its Competitive Outcomes | 소장 |
19 | The nature of local knowledge and new firm formation ![]() |
미소장 |
20 | Long-distance diffusion and strongly tied bridges: The influence of the originator's network ![]() |
미소장 |
21 | Managing the bossless team: Lessons in distributed leadership ![]() |
미소장 |
22 | Baudrillard, J. 1970. La Societe de Consommation. Paris: Gallimard. | 미소장 |
23 | Botton, A. 2004. Status Anxiety. NY: Pantheon Books. | 미소장 |
24 | Buchanan, J. 1975. The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. | 미소장 |
25 | Burns, T., & Stalker, G.M. 1966. The Management of Innovation. London: Tavistock. | 미소장 |
26 | Castells, M. 1996. The Rise of the Network Society. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishing. | 미소장 |
27 | Chandler, A. 1962. Strategy and Structure. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. | 미소장 |
28 | The Nature of the Firm ![]() |
미소장 |
29 | Toward a Behavioral Theory of Charismatic Leadership in Organizational Settings ![]() |
미소장 |
30 | Cyert, R., & March, J. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall. | 미소장 |
31 | Dworkin, R. 1977. Taking Rights Seriously. MA: Harvard University Press. | 미소장 |
32 | Ehrenreich, B. 2009. Bright-Sided. NY: Henry Holt and Company. | 미소장 |
33 | Fukuyama, F. 1992. The End of History and the Last Man. NY: Free Press. | 미소장 |
34 | Fukuyama, F. 1995. Trust: The social virtues and the creation of prosperity. NY: Free Press. | 미소장 |
35 | Gibbons, R. 2005. Four formal(izable) theories of the firm? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 58: 200-245. | 미소장 |
36 | Girard, B. 2009. The Google Way. CA: No Starch Press. | 미소장 |
37 | Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness ![]() |
미소장 |
38 | Communitarian Critics of Liberalism ![]() |
미소장 |
39 | Hackman, J.R., & Oldham, G.R. 1976. Motivation through the design of work: Test of a theory. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 16:250-279. | 미소장 |
40 | Hammer, M., & Champy, J. 1993. Reengineering the Corporation: A Manifesto for Business Revolution. NY: Harper Business. | 미소장 |
41 | The Project of Reconcilation: Hegel's Social Philosophy ![]() |
미소장 |
42 | Hart, O. 1995. Firms, Contracts and Financial Structure. Oxford: Clarendon Press. | 미소장 |
43 | Hayek, F.A. 1988. The Fatal Conceit. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. | 미소장 |
44 | The Negative Side of Positive Psychology ![]() |
미소장 |
45 | Huselid, M. 1995. The impact of human resource management on organizational performance. Academy of Management Journal, 39: 779-801. | 미소장 |
46 | The Effects of Human Resource Management Practices on Productivity: A Study of Steel Finishing Lines ![]() |
미소장 |
47 | Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure ![]() |
미소장 |
48 | Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process ![]() |
미소장 |
49 | What Firms Do? Coordination, Identity, and Learning ![]() |
미소장 |
50 | Performance Pay and Productivity ![]() |
미소장 |
51 | Lashinsky, A. 2012. Inside Apple. London: John Murray. | 미소장 |
52 | Lawrence, P., & Lorsch, J. 1967. Organization and Environment. Boston: Graduate School of Business, Harvard University. | 미소장 |
53 | Lyubomirsky, S., King, L., & Diener. E., 2005. The benefits of frequent positive affect: Does happiness lead to success? Psychological Bulletin, 131: 803-855. | 미소장 |
54 | MacDuffie, J.P. 1995. Human resource bundles and manufacturing performance: Organizational logic and flexible production systems in the world auto industry. Industrial and Labor Review, 48: 197-221. | 미소장 |
55 | MacIntyre, A. 1981. After Virtue: A Study in Moral Theory. London: Duckworth. | 미소장 |
56 | Schumpeterian patterns of innovation are technology-specific ![]() |
미소장 |
57 | Exploration and Exploitation in Organizational Learning ![]() |
미소장 |
58 | March, J., & Simon, H. 1958. Organizations. NY: Wiley. | 미소장 |
59 | Transaction Costs, Mistakes, and Performance: Assessing the Importance of Governance ![]() |
미소장 |
60 | The Costs of Organization ![]() |
미소장 |
61 | McGreger, D. 1960. The Human Side of Enterprise. NY: McGraw-Hill. | 미소장 |
62 | The Romance of Leadership ![]() |
미소장 |
63 | Miller, G. 1992. Managerial Dilemmas. New York, Cambridge University Press. | 미소장 |
64 | Mintzberg, H. 1983. Structure in Five: Designing Effective Organizations. NJ: Prentice Hall. | 미소장 |
65 | Nelson, R., & Winter, S. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. MA: Harvard University Press. | 미소장 |
66 | A Dynamic Theory of Organizational Knowledge Creation ![]() |
미소장 |
67 | Markets, Bureaucracies, and Clans ![]() |
미소장 |
68 | Pande, P.S., Neuman, R.P., & Cavanagh, R.R. 2000. The Six Sigma Way. New York: McGraw-Hill. | 미소장 |
69 | Pfeffer, J. 1994. Competitive Advantage through People: Unleashing the power of the work force. MA: Harvard Business School Press. | 미소장 |
70 | The Provision of Incentives in Firms ![]() |
미소장 |
71 | Prigogine, I., & Stengers, I. 1984. Order out of Chaos: Man’s New Dialogue with Nature. London: Heinemann. | 미소장 |
72 | Powell, W.W. 1990. Neither market nor hierarchy: Network forms of organization. Research in Organization Behavior, 12: 295-336. | 미소장 |
73 | Putnam, R.D. 2000. Bowling Alone. NY: Simon and Schuster. | 미소장 |
74 | Rawls, J. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. | 미소장 |
75 | A Pragmatic Theory of Responsibility for the Egalitarian Planner ![]() |
미소장 |
76 | Roethlisberger, F.J., & Dickson, W.J. 1939. Management and the Worker. CA: Harvard University Press. | 미소장 |
77 | Self-determination theory and the facilitation of intrinsic motivation, social development, and well-being. ![]() |
미소장 |
78 | Said, E. 1978. Orientalism. Pantheon Books. | 미소장 |
79 | Scott, W.R. 1987. Organizations: Rational, Natural and Open System (2nd. Ed.). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. | 미소장 |
80 | Schumacher, E.F. 1979. Good Work. NY: Harper & Row. | 미소장 |
81 | Schumpeter, J. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. NY: Harper and Brothers. | 미소장 |
82 | Selznick, P. 1957 (1984). Leadership in Administration. CA: University of California Press. | 미소장 |
83 | Simon, H. 1945. Administrative Behavior. New York: Free Press. | 미소장 |
84 | Organizations and Markets ![]() |
미소장 |
85 | Smith, A. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: Methuen & Co., Ltd. | 미소장 |
86 | Bureaucratic and Craft Administration of Production: A Comparative Study ![]() |
미소장 |
87 | Stinchcombe, A. 1990. Information and Organizations. LA: University of California Press. | 미소장 |
88 | Taylor, C. 1985. Philosophy and the Human Sciences: Philosophical Papers 2. NY: Cambridge University Press. | 미소장 |
89 | Taylor, F. W. 1911. The Principles of Scientific Management. NY: Dover Publications. | 미소장 |
90 | Thompson, J.D. 1967. Organization in Action. New York: McGraw-Hill. | 미소장 |
91 | Tirole, J. 1992. Collusion and the theory of organizations. In J. Laffont (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory: Sixth World Congress, Vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 151-206. | 미소장 |
92 | Weber, M. 1968. Economy and Society (G. Roth & C. Wittich. Eds.). Volumes 1 & 3. NY: Bedminster Press. | 미소장 |
93 | The Illusion of Leadership: Misattribution of Cause in Coordination Games ![]() |
미소장 |
94 | Whyte, W.H. 1956. The Organization Man. Simon and Schuster, Inc. | 미소장 |
95 | Williamson, O. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. NY: Free Press. | 미소장 |
96 | Williamson, O. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. NY: Free Press. | 미소장 |
97 | Deliberate Learning and the Evolution of Dynamic Capabilities ![]() |
미소장 |
98 | Zucker, L.G. 1986. Production of trust: Institutional sources of economic structure, 1840-1920. In Research in Organizational Behavior, 8: 53-111. CT: JAI Press. | 미소장 |
*표시는 필수 입력사항입니다.
*전화번호 | ※ '-' 없이 휴대폰번호를 입력하세요 |
---|
기사명 | 저자명 | 페이지 | 원문 | 기사목차 |
---|
번호 | 발행일자 | 권호명 | 제본정보 | 자료실 | 원문 | 신청 페이지 |
---|
도서위치안내: 정기간행물실(524호) / 서가번호: 국내09
2021년 이전 정기간행물은 온라인 신청(원문 구축 자료는 원문 이용)
우편복사 목록담기를 완료하였습니다.
*표시는 필수 입력사항입니다.
저장 되었습니다.